HOME
DV NEWS
SERVICE ARCHIVE SUBMISSIONS/CONTACT ABOUT DV
by
M. Shahid Alam
This is a
short history of the global economy since 1800. It is about the system of
global capitalism that took shape once the British economy went ‘underground’
and began to draw its energy and, increasingly, its raw materials from mineral
resources.
The progressive substitution of
minerals for plants, as the economy’s source of energy and raw materials, transformed
the dynamics of capitalism. It opened up vast new sources of energy and raw
materials, freeing the economy from the narrow resource constraints of an
organic, plant-based economy. The new cheaper, more abundant energy produced dramatic
reductions in the costs of transportation; a growing volume and range of goods could
now enter into long-distance and international trade; and this rapidly created
the basis for an international division of labor. But the resource substitution
also deepened the logic of uneven development. On the one hand, the
mineral-based economy created several positive feedbacks that strengthened the
already existing tendency towards the division of trading areas into Core and
Periphery, or concentrations of high and low value-added activities. In
addition, it augmented the military power of the states that pioneered these
new technologies. Together, these tendencies—markets, energy substitution, and
force—created the modern global economy, increasingly integrated but also
deeply divided into a Core and Periphery. [1]
The history of the new
mineral-based global economy falls into three phases, defined with reference to
the degree of global centralization of power. The first phase, lasting from
1800 to 1913, concentrated power—and, with it, capital, technology, science and
manufactures—in a small number of Core areas, notably Britain, France, United
States, and Germany. Conversely, the greater part of the Periphery—nearly all
of Asia and Africa—lost its sovereignty to a few Core countries, was forced to
open their economies to Core capital, specialized in primary goods, and
scarcely experienced any improvements in the living standards of the indigenous
population. The global economy slowly entered into a second phase in the late
1940s, although this process was initiated earlier with the Russian Revolution
of 1917, when power was decentralized from the Core to the Periphery. On the
level of the economy, this decentralization reversed the earlier concentration
of manufactures in the Core countries, and produced dramatic acceleration of
growth in the dependent Periphery. Starting in the 1980s, however, power was
again re-centralized in the Core countries. Already, by the mid-1990s, this
re-centralization had exceeded the previous peak in the global centralization
of power attained during the late nineteenth century. This paper will examine
these three movements of the global economy, though the emphasis will be on analyzing
the dynamics of the third movement.
Two Economic Logics
It is important to begin by
laying out, if only briefly, the different logics underlying the organic,
land-based economy that held center stage before 1800 and the inorganic,
mineral-based economy that has been developing since that date.
In the old agrarian system, two
factors perennially constrained its capacity for economic growth. This system drew
nearly all its energy from plants, the source of our food, fuel, fiber and
other raw materials; this constrained the supply of energy since the land
necessary for growing plants was available only in finite quantities. In
addition, this system only used organic instruments, men and animals, for
converting the energy captured by plants into mechanical energy. These organic
instruments did not favor growth since their upkeep required large amounts of
land, and their efficiency at converting energy could scarcely be improved
upon. As a result, once all accessible land had been brought into use, the
agrarian system grew by improving the organization of work, primarily through
division of labor; inventing machines that enhanced the efficiency of work; or
improving the quality of existing lands. The division of labor offered the best
prospects for growth, though this was limited—as Adam Smith so famously
noted—by the extent of the market, or transportation and institutions of
exchange. Most importantly, once all the land was in use, the limits on growth
pressed harder. It was land, or its ability to fix solar energy through plants,
that appeared to impose the final constraint on growth in this organic economy.
The new inorganic economy that
developed after 1800 transcended the dual limits that constrained growth in the
organic economy. It drew its energy and raw materials increasingly from stocks of minerals, and since these
stocks were quite large relative to the rate at which they could be drawn down,
this virtually lifted the cap on energy flows available to the economy. More
importantly, the energy from fossil fuels was converted to mechanical energy by
machines: the steam engine and, later, internal combustion engine. Once these
machines outstripped the organic instruments for converting energy to work,
they found growing applications in transportation, manufacturing, and,
eventually, agriculture. In time, the cheaper energy, when combined with
advances in science and technology, produced cheaper inorganic substitutes for
organic raw materials. This was in addition to the uses of fossil fuels, which
began at an earlier date, in heating homes, lighting and smelting.
This energy revolution created a variety of positive
feedbacks. First, the fossil fuels freed land from producing fuels and fodder;
the development of inorganic substitutes for organic raw materials had the same
effect. In other words, even as the new economy expanded, it released land that
could be used for producing more food and organic raw materials, and we can
expect this to reduce the industrial economy’s propensity to imports of food
and raw materials, at least during the early stages of this development.
Second, the cheaper energy reduced the costs of manufacturing and
transportation; in turn, the cheaper transportation produced cumulative cost
reductions in manufacturing through wider markets, greater division of labor,
technology spillovers, and other linkages. These cumulative cost-reductions
and, in part, their localized effects, created a tendency to concentrate the
world’s manufactures in countries—the Core countries—that took an early lead in
harnessing the new energy. Conversely, the rest of the world, the Periphery,
specialized in producing food and raw materials, still using the old source of
energy. Finally, the new energy per se
stimulated endless innovations in production technology. Since large and
increasing amounts of energy could now be concentrated at one point in space,
this led to the development of larger, faster, and more powerful machines for
use in transportation, manufacturing, mining, construction and, eventually,
agriculture. This constituted a third source of cumulative growth in the
industrial economy.
The energy revolution had created a new economic dynamics. Unlike the
muscle-driven, plant-based, land-constrained agrarian economy, the industrial
economy increasingly drew upon minerals for its energy and raw materials,
employed engines to convert fossil fuels to mechanical energy, and used this
energy to mechanize work in manufacturing, transportation, construction, and
agriculture. The productive capacity of the industrial economy was not
constrained by energy, as in the old agrarian economy, but by its ability to
deploy machines that converted energy to work. The engine of growth in this
economy was capital accumulation, since this determined how fast it could
expand the stock of energy-converting and energy-using machines available to
the economy. As a result, capitalists replaced landlords as the central actors
in the new industrial economy.
These profound changes created
new classes and class conflicts. The new energy-converting and energy-using
machines downgraded the workers in the manufacturing even as they pushed this
sector to the center of the economy. Of course, the workers were still needed,
but the new machines diminished their importance. Now the workers could not own
their machines, which were too expensive compared to what they were able to
save individually. The craftsmen, artisans, and even peasants, became labor,
hired by capitalists to tend to the machines, fix them when they broke down, or
perform tasks that had not yet been mechanized. The machines—and their
capitalist proprietors—now employed the workers. In addition, since the new
energy created concentrations of factories, it also assembled great masses of
workers in one workplace. These conditions favored the growth of class
consciousness on both sides of the production process.
The industrial economy deepened the polarizing tendencies in the agrarian
system. Formerly, due to the greater economies of scale in manufactures
compared to primary goods, there was a tendency for manufactures to be
concentrated in countries which acquired the biggest markets, whether by chance
or force. By reducing the costs of manufactures and transportation and creating
mineral-based substitutes for raw materials, the energy revolution strengthened
this tendency. In addition, both directly and indirectly, the energy revolution
added to a country’s military power by stimulating prosperity, reducing the
cost of arms and armaments, and improving military technology as inventors drew
upon the general advances in the economy’s technical capabilities. In time, the
development of steamboats, better prophylactics against tropical diseases, and
the development of rapid-firing weapons sealed the fate of Africa and Asia;
they were colonized or converted into open-door countries. [2]
The white-dominated Periphery in Europe and Latin America had the protection of
membership in the European family of civilized nations. [3]
The first countries to adopt the new energy system would have a
near-lock on the global economy. It created a set of cumulative forces that
concentrated manufactures, capital, technology and power in the countries that took
a lead in the energy revolution—the Core countries. Simultaneously, the new
energy system created a Periphery, economic regions that were restructured by
Core capital to supply food, agricultural raw materials and minerals to the
Core. In varying combinations, military force, markets and racist ideologies
brought about this restructuring. It is the story of this global economy that
we narrate in these pages.
Karl Marx and Class Contradictions
In his Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith (1776) does not once refer to any of
the early signs of an industrial revolution—the harnessing of waterpower, the
use of steam engine in mines, or the rise of factory production. Although he
was greatly impressed by the power of division of labor in manufacturing, he
believed that diminishing returns to capital and labor, in the presence of
fixed amounts of land, would eventually lead the economy into a stationary
state. This remained the vision of classical economists even as late as the
middle of the nineteenth century.
Amongst classical economists, Karl Marx (1848) alone
took serious notice of the industrial revolution. In graphic passages, he
describes the quickening pace of history, the tremendous expansive power of
capital, its constant search for new markets and new technologies, and how this
was pushing small-scale producers into the ranks of workers, and unleashing
profound changes in the economic and social landscape of pre-capitalist societies
everywhere. These transformations had produced two great classes, capitalist
and workers, constantly at odds with each other. At the global level, this
expansive dynamic was destroying pre-capitalist societies and binding them into
a single system of global markets. Although Marx did not worry too much about
the origins of capitalism—he saw its precursors in the burghers of medieval
towns, the growing commerce stimulated by the discoveries, and the system of
Atlantic trade—he was reasonably certain that the system he was describing was
fully developed or nearly so. Indeed, it was ready for another epochal
transformation, and he might even live to see that happen in his own lifetime.
As it was, Marx underestimated the durability of the system he was analyzing.
Class contradictions are central
to Marx’s analysis of capitalism. The two great classes spawned by industrial
capitalism, capitalists and workers, had opposite interests. The capitalists
were driven by competition to accumulate, innovate, and expand their market
shares; this produced concentrations of capital and deepening business cycles.
By the same logic, they sought to drive down wages and lengthen the workweek;
this pauperized the workers. At some point, Marx predicted, even in his own lifetime,
these two tendencies would produce a proletarian revolution. Led by the communist
party, the workers would overthrow the capitalists, abolish markets, socialize
ownership and production, and lay the foundations of a new social formation.
History did not oblige Karl
Marx. There would be no proletarian revolutions in the advanced industrial
countries, where capitalist contradictions were most ripe for the overthrow of
capitalism. The workers stirred in less likely places, but were easily
suppressed. On the whole, the class contradictions were contained, as
capitalist growth created a middle class, and rising labor productivity began
to translate into higher wages for production workers. In time, when the
workers organized, it was not to overthrow the system but to demand higher
wages and better working conditions. Slowly, capitalists acceded to these
demands, as unionized power expanded, workers gained voting rights, and labor
parties gained ground at the ballot. The emergence of the Soviet Union, the
first worker’s state, pushed Core capital towards greater accommodation with
their working classes. In addition, since there was little industrialization in
the Periphery yet, their concessions to labor did not dampen the international
competitiveness of Core capital. Finally, with help from compulsory schooling
and the media, the system succeeded in socializing the workers as citizens,
endowed with rights and the illusion that they were free to move up the social
ladder through education, thriftiness and hard work.
The challenges to Core capital
came from two sources not anticipated by Karl Marx: the rivalry of countries
seeking entry into the Core, and attempts by the Periphery to overthrow the
Core’s hegemony.
The outward expansion of Core capital was a central
result of Karl Marx’s analysis of capitalism. He never worried that anything
short of a proletarian revolution could reverse this expansion; it would
penetrate all parts of the world, and transform and launch them on development
trajectories similar to those traveled by the Core countries. Karl Marx had not
foreseen that the global expansion of Core capital, in and of itself, might
generate contradictions that would reverse for several decades the capitalist
penetration of the Periphery. We are indebted to Vladimir Lenin and the
neo-Marxists for drawing our attention to these contradictions.
Contrary to the mythical
accounts of orthodox economists, we observe an intimate connection between the
capital and the state at least in the rise of capitalism in Western Europe. In
the new age heralded by the energy revolution, capital in the Core countries
would use the expanded powers of the state to try to acquire exclusive control
over markets and resources in the Periphery. Starting in the nineteenth
century, this produced a new wave of direct colonization of societies – in
Asia, Africa and Caribbean – that did not have the protection of membership in
the Western “family of nations.” At
least for a while, the parceling of the world into colonies proceeded quite
smoothly. There was plenty of real estate for everyone.
The first challenge emerged when
powerful new entrants into the Core – Germany, Italy and Japan – were seized
with empire envy. The old timers,
Britain, France and Netherlands, had appropriated all the real prizes in Africa
and Asia. Miffed, the newcomers decided that their best chance of gaining an
empire was to take it from those who had one. In time, as Britain’s hegemonic
control weakened, this produced two fratricidal World Wars, fought mostly
amongst Western countries at the Core. According to an African proverb, when
elephants fight, the grass gets trampled on. In this case, whether by good or
ill luck, the grass would have a chance to grow.
Industrial capitalism spawned
powerful cumulative processes—operating through markets, military power and
racist ideologies of domination—which concentrated capital, manufactures,
technology and power in the Core countries. The dependent Periphery in Asia,
Africa and the Caribbean, regions that lost their sovereignty, specialized in
the production of primary goods for export.
The centralizing tendencies of
Core capital acted strongly and quickly. By 1913, according to Bairoch (1982:
296, 304), two-thirds of the world’s manufactures were concentrated in four
Core countries: Britain, United States, Germany and France. In 1750, their
combined share had stood at less than a tenth. At the same time, the Core
countries reduced vast areas of the world—nearly all of Asia, Africa, Central
America and the Caribbean—to colonies, open-door countries or dependencies,
which were converted to the production of primary exports. Those parts of the Periphery
that enjoyed various degrees of political autonomy were luckier. By 1950, many
of them had developed indigenous capital, skills and manufactures.
The contradiction between the
Core and dependent Periphery was on display, most transparently, in the
widening gap between the living standards of the two economic areas. According
to Bairoch (1981), Britain had roughly the same per capita income as Asia in 1800;
but, in 1950, it had gained a lead of close to six to one. Africa suffered a
similar decline in its relative position. On an average, the sovereign parts of
the Periphery did not face a decline in their relative position during this
period.
Once again, history had dashed
the great hopes of Karl Marx. Core capital had penetrated the Periphery—in
fact, its political penetration of the dependent Periphery was nearly
complete—but failed to transform its productive potential. Instead, the global
expansion of Core capital had polarized the world, dividing it into two unequal
moieties, the Core and the Periphery, connected by the disequalizing impact of
trade, imperialism and racist ideologies. In the words of Andre Gunder Frank,
capitalist development at the Core produced underdevelopment in the Periphery.
It is important to note that this inverse dynamic was strongest in the
relations between the Core countries and the dependent parts of the Periphery.
The prospects for growth in the
dependent parts of the Periphery were dim as long as they could not structure
their economic relations with Core capital. Yet, the system itself offered a
break. Help came when the elephants got into fights—big fights, better known as
World Wars. These wars battered the strength of the elephants, creating
opportunities for indigenous capital in the Periphery. When these wars directly
involved major countries in the Periphery—Russia in the First World War, and
China in the Second World War—they created openings for the emergence of radical
political movements. Thus was born the October Revolution of 1917, amidst the
chaos of Russian defeat during the First World War, producing the first
systemic challenge to Core capital. Ironically, the challenge had come from the
Periphery.
The October Revolution of 1917
began a temporary reversal in the global concentration of capital, power and
manufactures. It gave an impetus to liberation movements—in the colonies and
open-door countries—that were already challenging this concentration, even pushing
some towards radical solutions. The Soviet Union stood as the vanguard, the one
great ally, of liberation movements seeking to roll back the colonial empires
and weaken the polarizing dynamic of global capital. When the elephants fought
again twenty years later, these decentralizing movements were poised for major
victories.
Most importantly, the Second World War battered the
major colonial powers, those who won no less than those who lost. Of course,
the defeated powers, Italy and Japan, instantly lost all their colonies. The
victorious colonial powers, Britain, France, Belgium and Netherlands, found
that they had lost too much of their former strength to successfully defend
their empires, especially as the liberation movements gathered steam. In most cases,
they decided to pull out of their colonies before the anti-colonial movements
turned violent; this also offered the best opportunity of preserving their
economic interests and influence in the former colonies. A massive
decentralization of power followed, larger, more dramatic and deeper than the
one that marked the dismantling of Spain’s American empire in the 1820s.
This was a window of opportunity
for the Periphery, especially the former colonies and open-door countries who
were now free to restructure their relations with Core capital. Several tried
collective ownership and planning, and insisted on a radical break from global
markets. By the 1970s, nearly a third of the world’s population lived in
communist countries. Many more did not reject markets as such, but adopted a
variety of interventionist measures to develop indigenous capital, manufactures
and skills. Starting in the 1950s, the former colonies jettisoned the colonial
doctrines of laissez faire, free trade, balanced budgets, and private ownership.
In their place, they introduced interventionist policies to accelerate the pace
of development.
This decentralization produced
some dramatic results. The share of the Periphery – Africa, Latin America, and
Asia minus Japan – in world manufacturing
output had shrunk to 6.5 percent in 1953 from a dominant share of 73 percent in
1750. After two centuries of decline, this share began to increase in the
1950s, and rose to 12 percent in 1980. In addition, the growth rates in the
Periphery accelerated dramatically. The per capita income in the largest
colonies and quasi-colonies, containing some 50 percent of the world’s
population, grew at an average annual growth of 0.5 and -0.27 percent over
1900-1913 and 1913-1950; the same growth rates for the sovereign countries in
the Periphery were 1.61 percent and 1.34 percent. Over 1950-1992, the growth
rates in the former colonies and quasi-colonies had jumped to 2.96 percent,
ahead of the 2.58 percent recorded for the always-sovereign countries in the
Periphery. [4]
The retrenchment of Core capital would not last. Starting in the 1980s,
the IMF and World Bank began to dismantle the developmental states as their
mounting international debts pushed them closer to bankruptcy. A decade later,
the communist regimes began their transition to markets. In 1994, the creation
of WTO institutionalized the interests of Core capital.
It is tempting to take the position that this recentralization was inevitable.
An underdeveloped Periphery could not long resist the expansive power of the
Core countries once the latter had recouped their war losses and regained their
growth momentum. Yet, the communist revolutions and the liberation movements in
the Periphery came quite close to dislodging global capitalism. On closer
examination, the argument that revolutions in the Periphery were incapable of
overthrowing Core capital is not as watertight as it appears. In this case,
Core capital had geopolitical luck on its side.
The challenge from the Periphery was quite massive. The Soviet Union,
which mounted the systemic challenge to global capitalism, was a great power
itself. Its industrial and military strength expanded rapidly in the decades
following the Revolution, and, at the end of the Second World War, it had
emerged as one of the two superpowers dominating the world. In 1950, the
communist regimes in Soviet Union, Eastern Europe and China stretched
continuously from the Danube and the Balkans to the Pacific, together
controlling the upper half of the Eurasian landmass; they also contained nearly
a third of the world’s population. In addition, communist parties were active
in many Third World countries. At this point, many fully expected the tide of
communism to roll westward into a Europe devastated by war, and southward into
impoverished Asia and Africa. If, instead, Core capital successfully blocked
the communist advance and the Soviet Union itself collapsed in 1990, there was
nothing inevitable about these outcomes.
If Core capital overcame the communist challenge, this was, at least in
part, a fortuitous outcome of the system of nation states. The fact that United
States was the hegemonic power during this crucial period was a geopolitical
accident; there was nothing in the logic of capitalist system per se that produced this result. Yet,
this accident was of vital importance to the outcome of the contest between
Core capital and the communist regimes and nationalist liberation movements in
the post-war years. Imagine this contest with Britain still as the leading Core
country.
United States brought several vital advantages to this contest. The most
important was size. It had vastly greater resources than its predecessor,
Britain, had at its height. United States produced 44.7 percent of the world’s
manufacturing output in 1953 and 27 percent of the world’s output in 1950;
compare this to Britain’s peak share of world manufacturing output of 20
percent in 1860, and a share of 8.5 percent in world output in 1870. [5] American capitalism too was in some ways unique; it had a
huge industrial working class but they possessed little class-consciousness. As
a result, organized American labor joined enthusiastically in the fight to undermine
workers’ movements overseas. Capitalism—‘free enterprise,’ in the American
lingo—occupied a place in this country’s emotional life that normally belongs
to religion, inseparable from its national existence and history. The communist
challenge evoked very strong emotional defenses. Finally, the great distance of
United States from the theatres of war in Europe ensured that it would emerge
from the two World Wars with all its industrial assets in one piece.
The American strategy for containing communism required the commitment
of massive resources. The first component of this strategy was to put the
war-devastated economies of Western Europe and Japan back on their feet; some
of these economies had lost more than half of their pre-war production
capacities. The Marshall Plan was the centerpiece of these efforts. The United
States injected $11.8 billion into Western Europe between 1948 and 1952, equal
to $120 billion in 1997 prices. [6] In the words of
Duignan and Gran (1997), this amounted to the “greatest voluntary transfer of
resources from one country to another.” This injection of capital financed
technology transfers and the import of vital machinery, spare parts, and raw
materials, all of which put Western Europe’s industries back on their feet by
1952. In addition, the Marshall Plan pushed Western Europe towards economic and
political cooperation, helping to lay the foundations of a united Europe.
United States played a similar role in the recovery of Japan.
The second focus of America’s containment strategy was a massive
military buildup. During the Cold War, the military spending of United States
remained roughly proportional to its share in the global economy. In 1986, this
share was 28 percent of the world total and 65 percent of the NATO total. It is
even more remarkable that the Soviet Union, according to CIA estimates, outspent
the United States. In 1986, the military expenditures of United States and
Soviet Union were $365 billion and $374 billion respectively. [7]
Since the Soviet GDP was only 38 percent of the US GD in 1986, this must have
placed their civilian economy under considerable strain. [8]
Many experts maintain that this was an important factor in the eventual
collapse of the Soviet Union.
The containment strategy had a third focus. On the one hand, it consisted
of massive efforts to install anti-communist governments in the Periphery, prop
them with military and economic assistance, and use them to eradicate radical
movements in their own countries. The White House led these efforts with
support from several agencies including the United States Agency for International
Development (USAID). The Central Intelligence Agency (CIA) carried out the
opposite task of overthrowing or destabilizing governments that were
‘unfriendly’ to United States. A single statistic bespeaks better than many
tomes the power of this Agency: it spent $26.6 billions in 1997. [9]
The vast economic and military resources of United States allowed it to
maintain a firm hegemonic grip over the global capitalist system. On the one
hand, it created the NATO (North Atlantic Treaty Organization) to
institutionalize its military dominance over the Core countries in Western
Europe. In a similar move, Japan was converted into a military protectorate. In
the economic arena, United States sought to stimulate economic growth in
Western Europe and Japan by providing them relatively free access to its own
vast markets. In other words, the United States employed its dominant hegemonic
position to eliminate military conflicts among Core countries and, in addition,
replaced their economic rivalries with various cooperative arrangements,
including the European Common Market (ECM) and the Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD). Freed from their old conflicts, with
declining trade barriers, and better management of business cycles, the Core countries
went on to experience a golden period of growth between 1950 and 1973.
Core capital slowly regained its intellectual confidence and political
muscle as it grew and expanded, at home and abroad. On the economic front, this
was visible in the assault by neoclassical economists on Keynesian
macroeconomic policies, the regulation of industries, the welfare state and
social security programs. Politically, Core capital gained control over the
levers of power with the election of Prime Minister Thatcher in 1979 and
President Ronald Reagan in 1980, two right-wing warriors. The conditions were
now ripe for Core capital to stage a comeback.
We can agree on the factors that contributed to the collapse of communism
but still disagree on their relative importance. First, and I think foremost,
there was the geopolitical luck that placed the vast resources of the United
States in the fight to contain communism. This not only stopped the spread of
communism: it pushed the Soviets into a debilitating military rivalry even as
they failed to match the growing affluence offered by the Core countries. In
addition, the communist states were disadvantaged in their ideological battle
against Core capital. The Core countries captured the high ground on democracy
and freedoms, even while they sterilized the impact of these rights with
money-driven elections, media manipulation, and schooling. On the other hand,
the communists practiced inflexible planning, rejected political competition,
and stamped out dissent with police methods. They denied workers a sense of
ownership in their workplace, and when they also failed to deliver prosperity,
they had no chance of surviving. It was too late when the Soviets undertook
reforms in the late 1980s; this only deepened the feeling that the system was
indeed rotten, and hastened its collapse. China avoided this catastrophic end
by starting early on their economic reforms and delivering rapid economic
growth. However, their reforms too led to the same destination: the dismantling
of communism.
The end of developmental states came about differently. They had created
hothouses for the growth of indigenous capital in the Periphery, a prospect
that could not have pleased the Core countries. Since Core capital could not
block the progress of developmental states, they sought to penetrate them with
official loans, military agreements, private investments, technical assistance,
and access to the best graduate schools in the Core countries. In time, this
would produce results. Core capital penetrated the key sectors of the developmental
states, integrated their elites into the lower rungs of the Core hierarchy, and
oriented their most talented graduates into Core labor markets. Once started,
this process worked by undermining the developmental states.
Several forces inside the developmental states produced similar results.
In their anxiety to deliver growth on the cheap—without painful reforms—the
nationalists would seek loans from the Core countries, regardless of the hidden
costs, until their debt servicing placed them at the mercy of the lenders. In
their search for easy profits, the indigenous bourgeoisie forged links with
Core capital—as subsidiaries, suppliers, and distributors—and, once these ties
multiplied, they would lobby for the removal of barriers against the
penetration of Core capital. Finally, as some developmental states created the
infrastructure and skills that would make them increasingly competitive in
manufactures—threatening the Core countries with competition in their own markets—this
would invite predatory investment from Core capital, eager to ensure that they
owned the new industries developing in the Periphery. The strikes against developmental
states were mounting.
The dismantling of developmental states began in the early 1980s, well
before the end of the Cold War. It was triggered by the cumulative impact of
the two oil crises of 1974 and 1979. Unable to pay their higher import bills,
the oil-importing developmental states took out variable-interest loans from
foreign banks secured by sovereign guarantees. When interest rates rose in
1981, and some of these countries faced bankruptcy, the IMF and World Bank—the
watchdogs of Core capital—stepped into the breach, offering new loans to stop
them from defaulting on their old ones. At first, the borrowers were required
to stabilize their economies, which translated into cuts in their social
spending. This was the thin end of the wedge. In time, the conditionalities
were expanded into “structural adjustment programs”—a code word for
eviscerating the developmental states—which required eliminating trade
barriers, freeing exchange markets, privatization, and national treatment of
foreign investments.
The age of neoliberal economics had arrived. This was the new consensus
forged in the 1980s by a cohort of orthodox economists, many connected to the
World Bank and IMF. For several years, they had been developing a doctrinaire
neoclassical critique of developmental states—supported by several generously
funded, country-by-country assessments of the inefficiency of interventionist
policies in the developmental states. Their vision, appropriately dubbed the
“Washington Consensus” by John Williamson (1994), would tilt the playing field
in the Periphery to favor Core capital. In this new regime, the reformed states
would guarantee national treatment to Core capital, enforce property
rights—effectively, those of Core capital—balance their budgets, and help in
the provision of human capital. Core capital would step in to capture the
commanding heights—the financial sector, utilities, communications—and any
industry that offered handsome profits.
The end of the Cold War produced a push to institutionalize the interests
of Core capital in a new global framework. In 1994, this led to the creation of
the World Trade Organization (WTO), which bound all its members to a single set of rules—neoliberal rules—on trade,
exchange markets, foreign investments, government procurements, property rights
and investments. The WTO forced all countries to accord “national treatment” to
imports and foreign capital in every sector of the economy, including services,
thereby preparing the ground for rolling back the gains of developmental
policies. All this was a signal departure from the General Agreements on Trade
and Tariffs (GATT)—the trade regime displaced by WTO—which granted developing
countries the right to impose protectionist trade and payments regimes.
By the late 1990s, Core capital had reversed much of the decentralization
of power that had occurred since 1917. At no period during the past two
centuries did Core capital—not even during its previous peak in the late
nineteenth century—operate with so much freedom in nearly every country of the
world, or make deeper inroads into the Periphery. In effect, the WTO bound the
Periphery to the old open-door treaties minus
extraterritoriality; though in other respects the WTO was more invasive
than the open-door treaties, especially in the enforcement of property rights,
the penetration of services, and opening up government contracts to foreign
bids. In addition, the private agglomerations of Core capital in the 1990s were
now incomparably greater—compared to most countries in the Periphery—than they
were a hundred years back. This increased the capacity of Core capital to crowd
out, co-opt and absorb indigenous capital in the Periphery. Was this the
Valhalla of Core capital, the dream of the prophets of laissez faire?
Contrary to the grandiose claims
made by the ideologues, the neoliberal, open-door economic regimes imposed on
the Periphery by Core capital – starting in the 1980s – have produced no
economic miracles. Instead, these economic regimes have brought economic ruin
or, at best, lack-luster performance to the countries they have touched most
deeply.
In order to identify the failure of neoliberal economics, we will compare
the growth record of the Periphery in the two decades before and after 1980.
First, consider the two decades preceding 1980 when nearly all countries in the
Periphery protected their manufactures, regulated their currency markets,
engaged in deficit spending, and their governments took on entrepreneurial
roles. By the norms of neoliberal economics, they violated all the rules of
good economic housekeeping. Yet, they recorded quite impressive growth rates
under these interventionist regimes. The GDP of low-income countries grew at
average annual rates of 4.6 and 4.5 percent during the 1960s and 1970s; the
corresponding figures for the middle-income countries were 6.0 and 5.6 percent.
There were no strong regional variations in the growth record for this period.
Although growth in Sub-Saharan Africa faltered during the 1970s, there were
nine countries in this region whose average annual growth rates exceeded 5.0
percent during this decade. [10]
Over the next two decades, as the World Bank and IMF forced neoliberal
policies upon them, the growth rates in the Periphery declined in proportion to
their embrace of these policies. The neoliberal policies took their first toll
in Latin America and Sub-Saharan Africa. Both regions suffered a precipitous
decline in their GDP growth rates to 1.7 percent during the 1980s, producing
declining per capita incomes. The growth rates in Latin America recovered
during the 1990s to 3.4 percent per annum, though this was significantly below
their pre-1980 levels. The growth rate for Sub-Saharan Africa improved only
marginally during the 1990s, and it was unable to stem the decline in its per
capita income. [11]
The collapse of Eastern Europe and Central Asia came next, with their
rapid integration into global capitalism starting in the 1990s. Their economic
decline was striking. Although the growth performance of these economies had
been weakening for some time, they still managed to log an annual growth rate
of 2.4 percent in their GDP during the 1980s. However, their precipitate
transition to markets produced catastrophic results. During the 1990s, their
GDP declined at an annual rate of 2.7 percent, more than wiping out the gains
of the previous decade. It is doubtful if any economic region of comparable
size has experienced a similar decline in its output. Soon, their fertility
rates fell significantly below replacement levels, producing a declining
population. [12]
The economic decline of the Middle East and North Africa since the 1980s
has been nearly as steep as in Sub-Saharan Africa. Their GDP growth rates in
the two decades after 1980 were significantly below those for the two preceding
decades. As a result, the region’s per capita income declined between 1980 and
2000. This was not due to declining oil prices alone. The non-oil economies in
this region shared in this decline; their GDP had grown at 2.9 percent annually
between 1950 and 1980, but this declined to 1.5 percent in the two decades
after 1980. This decline occurred at a time when the non-oil economies, barring
Syria, were liberalizing their trade and payments regimes. [13]
Most countries in East and South Asia, which had made striking progress
in the transition to neoliberal economic regimes, followed the same pattern.
Their growth rates in the two decades after 1980 were visibly lower than in the
two preceding decades. Notably, this group includes the most advanced countries
in the region—Taiwan, South Korea, Singapore, Hong Kong, Thailand and
Malaysia—as well as the poorer countries: Sri Lanka, Indonesia, Philippines and
Pakistan.
There were few countries in the Periphery that escaped the declining
trend in growth rates in the post-1980 period. India and China, the two largest
countries in the Periphery with more than one-third of the world’s population,
nearly doubled their GDP growth rates in this period compared to their record
in the three previous decades. Although both countries enacted market reforms
since 1980, they were still amongst the most illiberal economic regimes in the
world, whether one examines the extent of state ownership in their industries
or their trade and payments regime. [14] A second group
of countries—Myanmar, Laos and Vietnam—experienced dramatic upturns in their
growth rates during the 1990s, without the benefit of a liberal regime.
These results should surprise no one but the historically myopic. In the
hundred years before 1950, the colonies and open-door countries performed
poorly compared to the sovereign countries in the Periphery—those that were
generally free to choose interventionist policies. [15] During
the post-war interlude lasting into the 1970s, when most of the former colonies
and open-door countries practiced strongly interventionist policies, they
experienced a dramatic acceleration in their growth rates. It is scarcely
surprising that the forced return to open-door policies in the Periphery, since
the 1980s, has repeated the results from the past. It is not clear how long
India and China, the two major countries that have not yet surrendered their
economic sovereignty, can resist conversion to neoliberal economic regimes.
The re-centralization of power by Core capital that began in the 1980s
was quite swift and mostly non-violent, unlike the centralization that reached
its peak in the last decades of the nineteenth century. Perhaps, this is not
surprising. The first centralization was a pioneering movement: it involved the
creation, extension and deepening of core-controlled systems of transport,
trade, finance, investment, cultural instruments, and subordinate classes in
the Periphery. It took centuries to establish this system, often involving
wars. However, when the colonial powers departed from their colonies, in most
cases, they did not fully liquidate these long-established systems of control.
While they terminated direct political controls, and ended their military
presence, many of the economic and social linkages, though weakened, persisted
in most former colonies; only the communist countries severed nearly all their
linkages with Core countries. This is what made the second re-centralization easier.
The Core countries began to reinforce their informal systems of control
as soon as they lowered their flags over their former colonies. The
reinforcements took many forms, including foreign aid, military assistance,
joint military exercises, training programs, and foreign investments. When Core
countries, now working in unison, articulated their new determination—through
IMF, World Bank and the OECD—to impose neoliberal regimes on the former
colonies in the 1980s, there was little resistance. For the most part, the
elites in the Periphery had already been integrated into the hierarchy of power
emanating from the Core; they also understood that resistance carried
unacceptable costs. There was no popular resistance because re-centralization
did not affect the visible symbols of sovereignty. The communist countries too
were re-integrated without firing a shot. They were overthrown from within,
since they failed to deliver prosperity, freedom or a sense of ownership.
Concluding Remarks
The swift and easy recentralization of the global economy created a paradoxical
situation. United States still commanded a massive military force while the
combined military strength of its main adversaries was less than a third its
former size. [16] This led to calls to downsize the
military, an intolerable prospect for the industries whose profits depend on
military contracts. This had to be remedied.
The refurbished power of Core capital was creating some domestic
problems too. On the one hand, Core capital was eroding the social gains made
by workers, consumers, and environmentalists since the 1930s. More importantly,
the labor force in the Core countries was beginning to face competition from
the growth of industrial production and advanced skills in some countries at
the Periphery. They were also losing jobs as Core capital relocated to the
Periphery, a process being accelerated by the internet revolution. In addition,
Core capital was using its muscle to import cheaper skilled workers into the
markets of Core countries. Faced with a sustained decline in their living
standards—the first in the history of industrial capitalism—a growing number of
people in the Core countries were gravitating towards anti-Corporatist,
anti-globalization movements. This too had to be remedied.
These problems would be solved by inventing new enemies. It was in this
context that Bernard Lewis (1990) first invented the “clash of civilizations”
between the West and Islam. He argued that the Islamist opposition in the
Middle East represented “a mood and a movement far transcending the level of
issues and policies and the governments that pursue them. This is no less than
a clash of civilizations – the perhaps irrational but surely historic reaction
of an ancient rival against our Judeo-Christian heritage, our secular present,
and the worldwide expansion of both in 1990, that the West was engaged in a
veritable clash of civilization with Islam.” Three years later, Samuel
Huntington (1993) generalized this thesis into a historical principle. At the
end of the Cold War, he prophesied, the world is entering a new age, whose
conflicts will occur along the fault lines of civilizations, mostly between the
West and Islam, and the West and China.
The Clash
thesis set up the military machine for capture by powerful special interests
and voting blocks within United States. Quickly, the Israeli lobby, Christian
fundamentalists, the oil interests, and military contractors joined forces.
Each would pursue its specific goal—eliminating threats to Israel’s hegemony,
Christianizing Islamic societies, capturing oil profits, resisting military
cuts—by mobilizing America’s redundant military to re-colonize the Middle East.
It was not hard selling this imperialist project to Americans. The Arab regimes
were easily painted into a corner. They were tyrannies, they possessed weapons
of mass destruction, they were an imminent threat to American lives, they
opposed Western values, and they threatened Israel. A great nation, the
greatest there has ever been, would have little difficulty manufacturing a
clash of civilizations when it needed one.
[1] The terms, organic and
mineral-based economy, are borrowed from Wrigley (1988: 12).
[2] Headrick (1981).
[3] Strang
(1996)).
[4] The data
in this paragraph are from Alam (2000): 151, 169.
[5] The data on shares of
manufacturing output are from Bairoch (1982: 296, 304), and the data on shares
in world output are from Maddison (1994): 182-3, 227.
[6] The
data are from Duignan and Gran (1997).
[7] The
data on military expenditures are from Conetta and Knight (1997).
[8] Maddison
(1995): 183, 187.
[9] Levin
(1997).
[10] World
Bank (1983): 150-51.
[11] World
Bank (2001): 295.
[12] World
Bank (2001): 295, 297.
[13] Sevket Pamuk, The Middle East
and North Africa in the age of globalization, 1980-2000 (Paper presented at
the 13th IEHA Congress at Buenos Aires, August 2002): http://www.eh.net/XIIICongress/cd/papers/7Pamuk
421.pdf
[14] Wacziarg and Welch (2002) maintain that India and China remained
closed economies as of 2000—India more than China—when judged in terms of their
average tariffs, non-tariff-barriers, and exchange-rate premiums. In addition,
state-ownership remained dominant in heavy industries in India; in China, this
included the financial sector as well.
[15] The average annual growth rates of PCI in the sovereign countries
were 1.00 percent for 1870-1900, 1.61 percent for 1900-1913, and 1.34 percent
for 1913-1950. The corresponding figures for the colonies and open-door countries
were 0.59, 0.50 and -0.27. Alam (2000): 151.
[16] In
1994, according to Conetta and Knight (1997) US military expenditure was $288
billion, while that of Potential Threat States was $167 billion; in 1986 the
corresponding figures were $365 billion and $550 billion.
Alam, M. Shahid, Poverty
from the Wealth of Nations (Houndsmill, UK: Macmillan, 2000).
Bairoch, Paul “The main trends in economic disparities since the Industrial
Revolution,” in: Paul Bairoch and Maurice Lévy-Leboyer, eds., Disparities in economic development since
the Industrial Revolution (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1981).
Bairoch, Paul, “International industrialization levels from 1750 to
1980,” Journal of European Economic
History 11, 2 (Spring 1982): 269-333.
Conetta, Carl and
Charles Knight, Post-Cold War US
military expenditure in the context of world spending trends
(Project on Defense Alternatives: January 1997): http://www.comw.org/pda/bmemo10.htm#2
.
Duignan, Peter and Lewis H. Gran, “The Marshall Plan,” Hoover Digest 4 (1997): http://www-hoover.stanford.edu/publicationsdigest974duignan.html
Headrick, Daniel R., The Tools
of Empire: Technology and European Imperialism in the Nineteenth Century
(New York: Oxford University Press, 1981).
Huntington, Samuel, “The Clash of Civilizations?” Foreign Affairs (Summer 1993).
John Williamson, eds., The Political
Economy of Policy Reform (Washington, D. C.: Institute for
International Economics, 1994).
Levin, Duncan, “The CIA and the price we pay: Law-suit response puts the
figure at $26.6 billion, Baltimore Sun
(October 19, 1997): http://www.gwu.edu/~cnss/secrecy/dloped.html.
Lewis, Bernard, “The Roots of Muslim Rage,” Atlantic Monthly (September 1990).
Smith, Adam, The Wealth of Nations:
An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes (Modern Library: 1776/1994).
Strang, David, “The Social Construction of Sovereignty,” in: Thomas J.
Biersteker and Cynthia Weber, eds., State
Sovereignty as Social Construct (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1996).
Wacziarg, Romain and Karen Horn Welch, “Trade Liberalization and Growth:
New Evidence (Palo Alto: Stanford University, November 2002): http://www.stanford.edu/~wacziarg/downloads/integration.pdf.
World Bank, World
Development Report, 1983
(New York: Oxford University Press, 1983): 150-51.
World Bank, World
Development Report, 2000-2001
(New York: Oxford University Press, 2001).
Wrigley, E. A., Continuity, Chance
and Change: The Character of the Industrial Revolution in England (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988).
M. Shahid Alam is Professor of Economics
at Northeastern University. His last book, Poverty from the Wealth of Nations, was published by Palgrave in 2000. He may be reached at m.alam@neu.edu.
Visit his webpage at http://msalam.net.
© M. Shahid Alam