by
Robert Brenner
Dissident Voice
March 8, 2003
At 6
a.m. on 12 June 2002, four FBI agents barged into the SoHo loft of Samuel
Waksal, the former CEO of the biotech company ImClone Systems Inc, and led him
away in handcuffs: he was charged with insider trading. His father and daughter
had dumped nearly 175,000 ImClone shares only days before the Food and Drug
Administration announced that it had rejected Erbitux, the compay's cancer
drug, leading to a steep price fall. (Waksal himself had netted $57 million on
an ImClone share deal the previous September, and had made an additional $72
million in 2001 from his stock options.) On 25 July, John Rigas, the former
head of Adelphia Communications, was arrested, along with his two sons, on
corporate crime charges. They were accused of using the company 'as the Rigas
family's personal piggy-bank', spending hundreds of millions of the
corporation's dollars on private jets, personal loans, luxury condominiums in
Colorado, Mexico and New York City - and on the construction of a $12.8 million
golf course. On 12 September, Dennis Kozlowski, the former chief of Tyco
International - and described by Business Week as 'perhaps the most aggressive
dealmaker in corporate America' - was put under arrest, charged with
fraudulently obtaining over $400 million by selling Tyco shares while
concealing information from investors. Kozlowski had used the funds to buy a
mansion in Florida, lavish properties in Boca Raton, Nantucket and New
Hampshire, a $7 million apartment for his first wife, diamonds from Harry
Winston and Tiffany's, and a fleet of fast cars and Harley Davidsons.
By August, the Wall Street
Journal's list of more than two dozen major corporations subject to official
investigation included such household names as AOL Time Warner, Bristol Meyers,
Dynegy, Enron, Global Crossing, Kmart, Lucent Technologies, Merck, Qwest,
Reliant Services, Rite Aid, Universal, Vivendi, WorldCom and Xerox. The two
largest US banks, Citigroup and J.P. Morgan Chase, are also being investigated,
as is Merrill Lynch. Meanwhile, the 'barons of bankruptcy', as the Financial
Times describes them - corporate insiders from the biggest 25 companies to go bust
last year - reaped $3.3 billion from stock sales and compensation in the three
years before their companies went under.
When corporate scandals
first hit the headlines early in 2002, the US Treasury Secretary Paul O'Neill
attributed them to the immorality of a 'small number' of miscreants. Apparently
he'd been misinformed. The rapacious practices of these executives and firms -
whether or not technically illegal - are typical of, and endemic to, corporate
America. The recent scandals bear witness, however, not just to the level of
individual corruption characteristic of US crony capitalism but to systemic
problems in the real economy. It is because the epidemic of fraud makes
manifest the ill-health of the corporations themselves that it has taken such a
heavy toll on investor confidence and the stock market.
The corporate account
rigging now coming to light is the direct result of the economic boom of the
late 1990s, driven by an almost unprecedented increase in equity prices. Its
raison d'être has been entirely straightforward: to cover up the reality of an
increasingly desperate corporate-profits picture. Between 1997 and 2000, just
as the fabled economic expansion was reaching its apex, the rate of profit in
the non-financial corporate sector was falling by a dramatic 20 per cent,
initially as a consequence of overcapacity in international manufacturing.
Under normal circumstances, this would have caused capital accumulation and
economic growth to slow. As it was, however, stock prices soared, in information
technology especially, even as corporate returns fell. Companies could thus
access funds with unprecedented ease, either by issuing shares at highly
inflated prices or by borrowing money from banks against the collateral of
those overpriced equities. On the basis of this financial windfall, US
corporations, especially in the IT industries, vastly stepped up their capital
accumulation. The investment boom continued, with increasing growth of output
and productivity. Even the staid academic economists of the Council of Economic
Advisers, not to mention the chair of the Federal Reserve, celebrated a new
synergy of technological change and freed-up financial markets that was
ushering in an unprecedented era of progress.
The catch, of course, was
that fast-rising profits are normally required to justify and support
fast-rising stock prices, as well as rapid investment. Instead, as investment
accelerated in the face of declining returns, overcapacity worsened, and the
fall in profitability extended from manufacturing to major high-tech industries
- above all, telecommunications. Faced with this patent failure of
'fundamentals', corporate executives were under mounting pressure to keep stock
prices high by any means necessary, in order to maintain access to cheap
finance and the investment funds required to compete; the fact that they had
come to depend heavily on stock options for their own compensation naturally
quickened the temptation. One after another great corporation falsified its
accounts to exaggerate short-term earnings.
But the economy could defy
gravity for only so long. From the middle of 2000, the reality of the profits
crisis became apparent as a never-ending parade of corporations, including
almost all the stars of the boom, were obliged to report increasingly dismal
earnings. Share prices began a steep descent, and investors gradually awoke to
the reality that they had been had. By this time the stock market was no longer
stimulating the economy: on the contrary, as their equity prices collapsed,
corporations were obliged to cut back on both borrowing and issuing shares,
making capital accumulation more difficult. The huge mass of superfluous plant
and equipment that was the legacy of the bubble-based misinvestment boom was
now apparent to everyone. Corporations were left with little reason to
accumulate new means of production, or labour, but with every reason to
initiate price wars. The economy plunged into recession.
To restore order, the
Federal Reserve brought down interest rates in record-breaking fashion, but
there was no response from corporations already overloaded with means of
production. Investment continued to decline, forcing up unemployment, reducing
demand and placing further downward pressure on prices and profits. An orgy of household
borrowing, largely against the collateral represented by private homes, enabled
the 'almighty consumer' temporarily to save the day. But this binge came at the
cost of a new bubble in the housing market, and is likely to have only a brief
half-life. Justified by 9/11 and a faltering economy - not to mention the
failure of the Fed's monetary policy - the Bush Administration has invoked the
need for both stimulus and security in order to rationalise a return to
Reagan's old formula of imperial adventure, tax cuts for the rich and increases
in military spending. But the proposed elimination of the tax on dividends
isn't aimed at raising demand any more than the war on Iraq, and its associated
expenditure on armaments, is supposed to increase Americans' safety. The
increased deficit that will result is intended, moreover, à la Reagan, to force
cuts in non-military expenditure, especially social services for the poor, and
this will act as some counterbalance to whatever stimulus it imparts. Only
barely invigorated by government policy, the economy totters towards the
precipice.
According to the official
story - told not only in Alan Greenspan's testimonies to Congress but in the
Council of Economic Advisers' Economic Report of the President 2001, the last
under the Clinton Administration - the stock market hothoused a technological
revolution in the 1990s which allowed the US economy, in contrast to its
laggard rivals in Japan and Western Europe, to escape from two decades of
stagnation. In this view, a 'new economy' focused on information technology had
emerged which, by significantly increasing the possibility of productivity
growth, opened up the potential for far higher profits. The stock market rose
to extraordinary heights in anticipation of these profits.
Financiers, the story goes,
naturally responded to these firms' elevated share prices by lending them
money, or buying their shares. Rising investment enabled the accelerated
introduction of new economy technology and thus productivity growth, which made
for even higher potential profits, higher share prices, better funding,
accelerated investment and so forth - what Greenspan called a 'virtuous cycle',
which issued, between 1995 and 2000, in what the Council of Economic Advisers
hailed as an 'extraordinary economic performance'. Since the stock market
provides investors with unmatched information as to the most promising firms
and industries, or so the theory goes, these would be expected to expand most
rapidly and drive the boom most efficiently. In particular, by offering
astronomical returns on the initial public offerings of the best new high-tech
start-ups, the stock market allowed venture capitalists to achieve otherwise
inconceivable rates of profit, and thereby to underwrite the fastest possible
technological change.
The reality of the expansion
of the 1990s bears little resemblance to the official version. The claim that
this was an 'extraordinary' boom is belied by the Government's own figures. In
terms of the standard measures - growth of output, capital stock, labour
productivity and wages, as well as the level of unemployment - performance in
the supposedly sensational five-year period between 1995 and 2000 barely
matched the levels achieved in the 25-year period between 1948 and 1973. The
growth of labour productivity, the most important indicator of economic
dynamism, was a full 20 per cent lower. Taking into account the whole business
cycle of the decade from 1990 to 2000 and not just the five good years at the
end, the average annual rate of growth of GDP per person was a meagre 1.6 per
cent, compared to 2.2 per cent for the hundred-year period 1889-1989. Even by
2000, real hourly wages for production and non-supervisory workers were still
palpably below, and the poverty rate above, their 1973 bests.
To grasp what drove the
economy in the 1990s demands a longer historical perspective. The economic
expansion during that decade took place against the background of the 'long downturn',
the era of slowed growth in the world economy that followed the long postwar
boom. Between 1973 and 1995 the growth of output, investment, productivity and
wages was one third to two thirds lower than during the previous quarter
century, while unemployment levels were several times higher (except in the
US). What was mainly responsible for the extended slowdown was overcapacity and
overproduction in the international manufacturing sector, which led, by way of
incessant downward pressure on prices, to reduced profitability - and the
failure of successive attempts made by corporations and governments
successfully to respond to this. The problem originated in the later 1960s as a
consequence of the intensification of international competition, which itself
resulted from the stepped-up entry into the world market of lower-cost
producers based in Japan, as well as Western Europe. During the 1970s,
overcapacity and overproduction worsened as leading firms in advanced
capitalist countries found that it made more sense to respond to their problems
with competitiveness and profitability by stepping up investment in their own
oversubscribed lines than by reallocating capital into new ones, thus
reproducing the initial problem. Meanwhile, firms based in the developing
economies, especially in East Asia, found they could enter certain lines at a
profit despite overcapacity. Only ever greater doses of Keynesian deficit
spending prevented the onset of deep crisis, but at the cost of runaway
inflation.
In the early 1980s, led by
Thatcher and Reagan, the US and the other advanced capitalist states introduced
high interest rates and deep austerity in order to encourage the shedding of
the high-cost, low-profit means of production that were holding down
profitability, as well as to raise unemployment in order to reduce wage growth.
But the immediate result was the outbreak of debt crisis in the Third World,
accompanied by the threat of depression in the US. Keynesianism had to be
reintroduced to keep the international economy turning over. The advanced
capitalist states were clearly unwilling to sustain a severe depression of the
sort that, in the past, served to eliminate superfluous means of production and
labour and to provide the foundation for an upturn. But the price of economic
stability was a rise in interest rates to record-breaking levels, which, in
combination with still reduced profit rates, reined in capital accumulation and
economic growth, which remained heavily dependent on government deficits until
the end of the decade.
Appearances to the contrary,
the long downturn was not transcended even during the 1990s. Between 1990 and
1995, the advanced capitalist economies suffered their worst half-decade of the
postwar epoch. For the decade as a whole, their performance taken together was,
despite the US boom, hardly better than that of the 1980s; which itself was
down from the 1970s; which, in turn, had been much worse than the 1960s and
1950s.
It was against the
background of a slow-growing global economy that the US launched its economic
revival. Between 1985 and 1995, the US manufacturing sector used an impressive
recovery of international competitiveness to achieve an increase in
profitability that was responsible for bringing the profit rate in the private
economy as a whole above its 1973 level for the first time since the end of the
1960s. By 1994, this rise in profitability had set the stage for the investment
boom that would be the main source of economic dynamism in the later 1990s; US
economic expansion had begun in earnest.
The means by which the
manufacturing sector achieved its recovery of profitability were typically
destructive. The Plaza Accord, imposed by the US Government on its leading
partners and rivals in 1985, led to a 40-60 per cent fall in the dollar against
the yen and the deutschmark over the following ten years, dramatically lowering
the cost of US goods compared to those of its main competitors. Employers held
real wage growth close to zero for the whole decade. The Reagan Administration
slashed corporation taxes. While investment continued to stagnate until 1993,
companies shed masses of high-cost, low-profit means of production and labour
in order to raise productivity.
But the fact that the US's
recovery of profitability was the result mainly of corporate downsizing and the
gouging of workers, citizens and overseas rivals proved highly problematic for
the two next largest economies, the Japanese and the German. For most of the
period there was little growth in US aggregate demand. Demand for plant and
equipment and for consumption goods both stagnated. Government demand fell,
too, as from 1993, the Clinton Administration - going back on America's
historical willingness to sustain deficits to stimulate the global economy -
turned to balancing the budget. Meanwhile, US manufacturers' reductions in
relative costs through wage restraint, productivity increase and dollar
devaluation allowed them to appropriate world market share from their
competitors in Japan and Germany.
The outcome was that during
the early 1990s German and Japanese manufacturing profitability fell sharply
just as the US was assembling the basis for its boom. This hydraulic pattern -
by which the recovery of one manufacturing economy would find its counterpart
in the crisis of another as the exchange rate shifted - reflected the system's
slowed growth, and would be repeated time and again. From 1991 both the
Japanese and German economies experienced their worst recessions of the postwar
epoch. By 1995, there had still been no palpable recovery in the advanced
capitalist economies as a whole. The long downturn was alive and well.
In the spring of 1995 the
yen rose to 79 to the dollar; as recently as 1985 it had stood at 240. The
Japanese manufacturing economy, obliged to absorb this enormous increase in the
relative cost of its goods on the world market, seemed on the verge of freezing
up. Having just weathered the international disruption caused by a major
financial crisis in Mexico that had reverberated throughout Latin America, the
US Government could not allow the Japanese economy to fail. Japan's economy was
second only to that of the US, and a crisis there would pose a threat to
international stability. The country was also the US's leading creditor, and a
Japanese crisis would probably have led to a fire sale of US bonds, forcing up
interest rates and cutting short the American recovery in the run-up to the
1996 elections. With the so-called 'reverse Plaza Accord' of summer 1995, the
US Government therefore agreed with its Japanese and German counterparts to
drive up the dollar.
This agreement constituted a
turning point in the evolution of the world economy. It reversed the dominant
economic trends of the previous decade and, in a crucial sense, prepared the
way for every major development of the next five years: the decline of US
profitability, the historic equity price increase, the stock market-led
economic boom - and the crash and recession that have followed.
The first, and most
consequential, effect of the dollar revaluation was to put an abrupt end to the
decade-long recovery of US profitability. Between 1997 and 2000 the corporate
manufacturing profit rate dropped by more than 15 per cent, so that the US
economy lost what had up to this point been a major source of its momentum.
This sudden increase in pressure on the rate of profit posed a threat not just
to the US but to the entire world economy. To counter the long downturn, and
the reductions in profitability that lay behind it, governments and corporations
across the globe had been taking ever more stringent measures to reduce costs.
But the unavoidable by-product of their offensive had been the shrinking growth
of aggregate demand across the system, which now threatened to short-circuit
international economic recovery. Wage and social spending increases had been
cut back increasingly sharply over the 1970s and 1980s. In the run-up to
monetary union, European governments had imposed even tougher austerity
measures, and the Clinton Administration had followed suit.
In the context of
increasingly sluggish domestic markets, the rest of the world was obliged to
look to the US market to provide the export demand to keep their economies
going. But with American wage growth flat and government demand rapidly shrinking
after 1993 as the Federal deficit fell, dependence on the US market translated
into ever greater dependence on the growth of US investment - which, it was
hoped, would result in greater imports both of new plant and equipment and, by
way of higher employment and rising wages, of consumer goods. With the new
downward stress on the manufacturing profit rate deriving from the rise of the
dollar, however, the capacity of the US to serve as the 'market of last resort'
appeared under threat.
And yet, from 1996, US
economic expansion took on a new dynamism, and carried the rest of the world
along. What increasingly drove it was a stock market that soared to unmatched
heights, despite the weakening of corporate profitability from 1997. Between
the early 1980s and 1995, the rise of equity prices had been no greater than
the rise of profits. Henceforth, a growing chasm would open up between the two.
As the Wilshire 5000 Index soared 65 per cent between 1997 and 2000, corporate
profits (after tax and net of interest) fell by 23 per cent.
What laid the basis for the
stock market's dizzying ascent was a major, long-term easing of credit. This
resulted, initially, from the same co-ordinated move in 1995 by the G3 powers
to drive up the dollar that had brought about growing downward pressure on the
US manufacturing profit rate. To push down their own currencies relative to the
dollar, the Japanese - and other East Asian governments - bought US assets,
especially Treasury instruments, in massive quantities. The resulting flood of
money on US markets brought about a sharp reduction in long-term interest
rates. Meanwhile, seeking to secure stability in the wake of the Mexican
financial crisis, the Federal Reserve lowered short-term interest rates.
Investors took advantage of the declining cost of borrowing to pour money into
the stock market, driving up equity values. And with the dollar going up, stock
prices automatically rose in value in international terms, which attracted more
investment that, in turn, drove the stock market even higher.
What seems puzzling is that
the process did not stop there, once the gap between share values and profit
rates had begun to open. By late 1996, Greenspan was publicly expressing
concern about the 'irrational exuberance' of share prices. But he was clearly
even more anxious, in private, about the possible stumbling of the US economy,
especially as economic growth at first proved hesitant in the face of his
interest-rate reductions and as turmoil shook the East Asian markets in spring
1997. In this context, as he was well aware, the 'wealth effect' of a rising
stock market could play a stimulating and steadying role, funding investment
growth and consumer demand that could compensate for declining government
deficits and the negative impact of the rising dollar on profit rates. If the
prices of their equities rose, corporations would be able to access otherwise
unavailable funds for investment, either by issuing over-valued shares or by
borrowing from the banks. By the same token, households with rising paper
wealth would find less need to save.
In undertaking the US's
first essay in what might be termed stock-market Keynesianism, Greenspan, far
from seeking to control the bubble, actively encouraged it. He not only welcomed
the enormous increase in liquidity resulting from the influx of foreign money
and his own reduction of interest rates, but also refused to raise the cost of
borrowing from the beginning of 1995 until mid-1999 (aside from a lone
quarter-point rise in early 1997) or to raise the required margin on share
purchases to discourage speculation. He intervened vigorously by loosening
credit whenever the equity markets threatened to swoon - most spectacularly in
autumn 1998, at the nadir of the world financial crisis. As a result, from 1995
until 1999, the money supply (M3) increased at six times the rate it had from
1990 until 1994, opening the way for a gigantic wave of speculation.
US corporations, in
particular, were quick to exploit the easy money Greenspan was pouring their
way. Between 1995 and 2000, they increased their borrowing to record levels as
a percentage of corporate GDP; not only to fund new plant and equipment, but
equally to cover the cost of buying back their own stocks. In this way, they sidestepped
the tedious process of creating shareholder value by producing goods and
services at a profit, and directly drove up the price of their shares for the
benefit of their stockholders and for corporate executives, who were heavily
remunerated with stock options. Between 1995 and 2000 US corporations were the
largest net purchasers on the stock market.
Still, the availability of
easy money can provide only an incomplete explanation of the great equity price
run-up. After all, the low cost of credit cannot make people borrow with the
intention of speculating; yet speculation - by mutual funds, insurance
companies, pension funds and other such institutions - was indispensable to the
expansion of the bubble. To explain why money continued to pour into corporate
equities even as corporate profits stagnated, one has to turn to the peculiar
way finance works, and the tendency of its operatives towards herd behaviour.
As equity prices began to rise strongly from early 1996, fund managers were
under heavy pressure to buy, even if they doubted the long-term viability of
their purchases. If they failed to do so, they risked falling behind their
competitors and losing their jobs. On the other hand, if, in the long run, the
assets they had purchased went sour, they could not be held responsible, since
so many others had done the same thing.
As a result of the
historically unprecedented ascent of their share prices, corporations were able
to avoid facing up to the unpleasant reality of declining returns and to sustain
the long expansion of the 1990s right through to the end of the decade. The
magnitude of the wealth effect celebrated - and bolstered - by Greenspan and
others was unprecedented. Historically, US corporations had been largely
self-financing, paying for their investments largely out of retained profits.
By the end of the 1990s, however, they were borrowing at record-breaking levels
(compared to output) in order to fund investment, while also financing
themselves by way of equity issues to a degree never remotely approached
before.
Wealthy households also saw
their on-paper assets rise astronomically. According to a recent Federal
Reserve study, the top 20 per cent of wealth holders could account, by
themselves, for the spectacular reduction of the US household savings rate from
around 8 per cent in 1993 to zero in 2000. In so doing, they also accounted for
the increase in the rate of consumption that took place during that period,
helping corporations realise their skyrocketing investments on plant, equipment
and software. In the words of one pundit, this was the first expansion in
history underwritten by 'yuppie consumption'.
Thanks to the wealth effect
of the stock-market increase, especially in information technology, the
expansion did achieve increasing vitality. Non-residential investment grew by 9
per cent per annum for the rest of the decade, driving the boom. This made for
a rapid growth of output, decent productivity growth, falling unemployment and
even, eventually, significant wage increases. Last but not least, the huge
increase in US demand that resulted from the speeding up of the expansion, plus
the still rising dollar, first pulled the world economy from its doldrums of
the early 1990s, then rescued it from the international financial crisis of
1997-98 and ultimately incited a new international economic upturn in 1999 and
2000.
The fact remains, however,
that a stock-market rise driven by speculation, far from discerning the most
promising fields for expansion - as it does in the fables of the Federal
Reserve, the Council of Economic Advisers and orthodox economic theory - was
systematically misdirecting investment, because it was not based on rising
rates of return. The rapid growth of expenditure on plant and equipment in new-
economy industries took place against a background of falling profitability in
manufacturing; that decline soon extended to information technology and
telecoms. Productivity growth increased, but could not lead to a raising of the
rate of return because it resulted from the same overinvestment that was
simultaneously creating overcapacity and overproduction. The consequent
downward pressure on prices benefited consumers in the short run; but by
forcing down profits, it limited investment, growth and employment in the longer
term. Between 1997 and 2000, as the boom peaked, the rate of profit in the
non-financial corporate sector as a whole fell by a fifth.
The 'virtuous cycle' touted
by Greenspan was little more than hype. What drove the economy during the
second half of the decade was a vicious cycle that proceeded from rising equity
prices to rising investment, in the face of falling profitability, which issued
in increasing overcapacity that lowered profitability still further. It was the
increasing defiance of gravity by both the booming economy and the bubbling
stock market that opened the way to the corporate accounting scandals, the
stock-market crash and the new recession.
This economic process worked
itself out most dramatically in the IT sector and, especially, in telecoms. The
high-tech frenzy was prompted by Clinton's 1996 Telecommunications Act, which
deregulated the telecoms market. A phalanx of new entrants rushed in, hoping to
capitalise on what they took for granted would be an unprecedented growth of demand,
generated by the endless expansion of the Internet. By virtue of what they
assumed would be their technological superiority, they also counted on wresting
market share from such giants as AT&T, Sprint and Verizon. Their strategy
was focused on the stock market and finance. By expanding through mergers and
acquisitions with the greatest possible speed, they sought to win the approval
of equity markets - dazzling them with size and growth, rather than profits. On
this basis, they aimed to drive up share prices and thereby find the finance
they required for further growth.
The emerging telecoms
companies were soon laying tens of millions of miles of fibre-optic cable
across the US and under the oceans, with the indispensable assistance of
America's leading financial institutions - above all, its greatest banking
conglomerates. These 'one-stop' financial supermarkets had emerged from an ever
deepening process of financial deregulation, closely overseen and patronised by
the Clinton Administration and a Democratic Party leadership determined to
exploit the hugely increased fund-raising opportunities they knew would
materialise from their embrace of the neoliberal programme and, in particular,
the agenda of the great banks. Under the watchful supervision of Robert Rubin,
who, having been CEO at Goldman Sachs, was made Clinton's Treasury Secretary in
1993, the already disintegrating barriers between investment banks, commercial
banks and insurance companies - originally erected by the New Deal, in response
to the 1990s-style excesses of the 1920s - were obliterated.
The climax came in April
1998 when Travelers Insurance, owners of the investment bank Salomon Smith
Barney, merged with the commercial bank Citicorp to form Citigroup, in direct
defiance of the still valid Glass-Steagall Act, the pivotal piece of New Deal
legislation regulating finance. These giants were clearly confident that the
Government would sanction the merger - and with good reason: Citicorp donated
$4 million in campaign contributions during the 1996 and 1998 electoral cycles.
The finance, insurance and real-estate industries spent over $200 million on
lobbying during 1998 and donated another $150 million in the course of the 1998
electoral campaign. Above all, the newly merged mega-bank knew it could count
on Rubin, and the Treasury Secretary didn't let them down. He made sure that
Congress permitted their merger and was promptly rewarded when, five months
after resigning his post in the Clinton Administration, he was appointed
chairman of the executive committee of Citigroup, now the country's largest
financial institution.
The banking monoliths that
arose from the financial deregulation process were supremely well placed to
garner the fees for underwriting the share issues, floating the bonds and
organising the mergers and acquisitions of the newly deregulated telecoms
industry. It was therefore only natural that they encouraged - and enabled -
the telecoms firms' obsession with expansion. They were pleased, too, in their
role as commercial banks, to lend their clients however much money they wanted
(sometimes at below market rates), so long as they could secure, in their role
as investment banks, these companies' underwriting business and the associated
fees. They were all too ready, as well, to invoke the latest innovations in
'structured finance' to help their clients improve the appearance of their
corporate balance sheets, keeping their equity prices soaring, their
money-raising capacity unimpaired, and thus their demand for financial services
expanding. In the half-decade after 1995, the top ten banks organised 1670
mergers and acquisitions valued at $1.3 trillion for telecommunications
companies, receiving from them $13 billion in fees.
These same banks were also
more than pleased to advise the ostensibly independent 'stock analysts' that
they employed on how to value the shares of their client corporations, in the
unlikely event of those analysts being mesmerised by the reality of their
insufficient returns. Nor were they above straightforwardly bribing their
corporate customers by handing their chief executives millions of dollars'
worth of shares, often initial public offerings, in order to secure their
financial business - this is not illegal unless it can be proved that
forwarding the stock was an explicit condition for contracting the service.
Meanwhile, the country's longest-established accounting firms, who had come
increasingly to double as investment consultants for the very companies whose
books they were supposed to be auditing, kept the game going by turning a blind
eye to their clients' financial shenanigans.
Salomon Smith Barney, the
investment-banking arm of Citigroup, played the vanguard role in this process,
led by its communications analyst, Jack Grubman, who pushed his clients to
cough up billions of dollars for fibre optics, saw to it that Salomon got to
raise the money for them, then praised their shares to the equity-investing
public. 'What used to be a conflict of interest is now a synergy,' he assured
readers in a profile published in Business Week in 2000. After the passage of
the Telecommunications Act, Salomon helped 81 telecoms companies raise some
$190 billion in debt and equity. For its efforts, it received hundreds of
millions in underwriting fees and tens of millions more for advice on mergers
and acquisitions. Especially privileged were those heading Salomon's A-list of
rising telecoms stars - WorldCom, Global Crossing and Qwest. Salomon raised
$24.7 billion, $5.4 billion and $5.6 billion respectively for these three
companies and received from them $140.7 million, $83.8 million and $34.4
million in fees. Although it was technically illegal, to smooth the way for
these deals Salomon routinely rewarded the executive involved with the hottest
initial public offering shares, handing Bernie Ebbers, the WorldCom CEO, IPOs
that cashed out at over $11 million.
Such behaviour was emulated
by all the other top investment banks and their communications analysts. Fund managers
who stayed away from telecoms equities risked falling behind their competitors,
with the result that institutional investors ended up buying shares as if there
was no tomorrow, driving their values into uncharted territory. Meanwhile,
manifesting the herd behaviour for which they are notorious, commercial banks
showered the telecoms industry with more funds than it could sensibly invest,
force-feeding expansion and insuring overcapacity. Time and again, Keynes's
famous 'beauty contest' dynamic drove the inherently speculative process: to
maximise profits, financiers had little choice but to base their investment
decisions on their best guess as to what assets everyone else would be deciding
to buy and sell in the short run, not on their own evaluations as to the
intrinsic long-term worth of those assets.
By spring 2000, at the apex
of the stock market's ascent, the market capitalisation of the telecoms
companies (the value of their outstanding shares) had reached a staggering $2.7
trillion, or close to 15 per cent of the total for all US non-financial
corporations - this despite the fact that they produced less than 3 per cent of
the country's GDP. With such enormous apparent collateral, telecoms firms could
borrow without limit. Between 1996 and 2000 they took on $800 billion in bank
debt and issued an additional $450 billion in bonds. On this basis, they were
able to increase investment over this period in real terms (i.e. measured in
1996 dollars) at an annual average rate of more than 15 per cent, and to create
331,000 jobs.
The problem, of course, was
that thanks to the unregulated product and financial markets, everyone was
doing it. In 2000 no fewer than six US companies were building new, mutually
competitive, nationwide fibre-optic networks. Hundreds more were laying down
local lines and several were also competing on sub-oceanic links. All told, 39
million miles of fibre-optic line now criss-cross the US, enough to circle the
globe 1566 times. The unavoidable by-product has been a mountainous glut: the
utilisation rate of telecom networks hovers today at a disastrously low 2.5-3
per cent, that of undersea cable at just 13 per cent. There could hardly be
clearer evidence that the market - and especially the market for finance - does
not know best. The consequence was an amassing of sunk capital that could not
but weigh on the rate of return for the foreseeable future, in the same way as
did the railway stock built up during the booms of the 19th century.
Even as their equity prices
soared and their purchases of new plant, equipment and software escalated, the
telecoms companies found it impossible to make a profit. Having reached a peak
of $35.2 billion in 1996, the year of deregulation, corporate profits (after
the payment of interest on company debt) in the communications industry sank to
$6.1 billion in 1999, and then to minus $5.5 billion in 2000 as interest
payments on their gargantuan debt shot up.
Against this background of
falling returns, rising investment and growing debt, the pressure to sustain
elevated equity prices in order to maintain the flow of finance became ever
more intense, and the temptation to inflate profits via fraudulent book-keeping
apparently irresistible. Here Salomon's stable of telecoms upstarts led the
way. Global Crossing and Qwest began to 'swap' business as a matter of routine,
one company leasing out its own lines to the other while leasing back
equivalent lines for its own use, recording the returns from the former as
income and booking the latter as if it were depreciation on plant and equipment
over a number of years. By this method, both companies inflated revenue by at
least $1 billion in 2001, an amount probably significantly greater than each
one's recorded profits. Both companies are now facing criminal investigations,
although it was only in August 2002 that the Securities and Exchange Commission
explicitly outlawed such procedures. So much for government oversight.
But the crimes of Global
Crossing and Qwest are peccadillos compared with the grand larceny carried out
by WorldCom, which has effectively rewritten the book on corporate fraud. At
the most recent count WorldCom had overstated its earnings between 1999 and
2001 by some $9 billion. It accomplished this largely (though not entirely)
through the simple ruse of treating expenditures on day-to-day items like wages
as if they were payments for capital goods. They could thus record them as
depreciation and put off into the future their appearance as costs on the
company's balance sheet.
When asked, in an internal
audit just before the fraud became public (revealed in the Wall Street Journal,
16 July 2002), how he would justify the company's treatment of expense to the
SEC, the WorldCom company controller, David Myers, acknowledged that he 'had
hoped it would not have to be explained'. On the other hand, he countered, if
WorldCom's reported costs weren't somehow reduced and its profits enhanced,
'the company might as well shut its doors.'
Crucial to this corporate
dissimulation were Wall Street's accounting norms, which legitimate virtually
any trick in the book to pump up 'pro-forma' earnings - those that are reported
quarterly to stockholders and the financial community. It is only later that
companies are obliged to own up to their real earnings, calculated according to
strict 'Generally Accepted Accounting Principles' (GAAP), to the Securities and
Exchange Commission. Needless to say, this system of dual reporting invites
abuses - for instance, exaggerating short-term earnings just long enough to sustain
equity prices while corporate insiders unload their stock. To give an idea of
the scale of misrepresentation involved: a recent study by
SmartStockInvestor.com revealed that, for the first three quarters of 2001, the
Nasdaq 100 companies reported pro-forma profits of $19 billion to their
shareholders, but GAAP losses of $82 billion to the SEC. Microsoft, Intel,
Cisco Systems, Oracle and Dell, taken together, overstated their profits for
the same period by a factor of three.
The reason the scandals have
hit the stock market and the economy so hard is that they have confirmed
investors' worst suspicions about plummeting corporate returns. The revelation
of WorldCom's fraud shook the markets because it became perfectly clear that
what had appeared to be one of the most successful companies in the telecoms
business had made no profits in either 2000 or 2001 (and quite possibly not in
1998 or 1999 either). WorldCom, as one analyst told Fortune in July 2002,
'seemed to have some kind of secret formula for producing decent margins where
rivals couldn't'; when this formula was understood the last bit of air went out
of the telecoms bubble.
Still, it should not be
thought that the entrepreneurs behind the great telecoms bust were so clumsy as
to get caught up in the financial carnage they left in their wake. Between 1997
and 2001, insiders cashed in some $18 billion in shares, unloading more than
half this total in 2000, the year the price of telecoms shares peaked. But this
only scratches the surface of the titanic redistribution of wealth achieved by
US corporate leaders in the 1990s. Between 1995 and 1999, the value of stock
options granted to US executives more than quadrupled, from $26.5 billion to
$110 billion, or one fifth of non-financial corporate profits, net of interest.
In 1992, corporate CEOs held 2 per cent of the equity of US corporations;
today, they own 12 per cent. This ranks among the most spectacular acts of
expropriation in the history of capitalism.
The economic rationale
underlying the great telecoms bubble was the assumption that demand for
Internet services would increase exponentially, leading to a comparable demand
for extra bandwidth. The massive expansion of telecoms carriers that was
expected to result constituted the premise for a parallel explosion in the
manufacture of telecoms-carrier equipment and, in turn, for the
component-makers for telecoms-carrier-equipment manufacturers. The bust, when
it came, thus proceeded from the dot.coms, via the telecoms carriers, to the
equipment suppliers and their component makers.
The dot.com bubble was as
impressive, in its way, as the telecoms bubble. Despite their infinitesimal
contribution to GDP, the stock-market value of Internet firms eventually
reached 8 per cent of the total for all US corporations. The reality was that
most of these companies made only losses, and the few that were making profits
were trading at impossibly high price-earning ratios. In a sample of 242
Internet companies studied by the OECD, only 37 made profits in the third
quarter of 1999, with just two of them accounting for 60 per cent of the total
amount. For the 168 companies for which detailed data were available, losses in
the third quarter amounted to $12.5 billion - but this did not prevent their
market capitalisation from reaching $621 billion. By spring 2000, in the wake
of continuing losses, many of these e-businesses were simply running out of
money. The crash and then the collapse of the industry followed soon after.
The bursting of the Internet
bubble was the catalyst for the telecoms bust, which began in the summer of
2000 with a seemingly unending series of disastrous high-tech earnings reports.
The new economy rout was on. Communications industry profits fell by $5.8
billion in 2001 and $11.9 billion in 2002. By the middle of 2002, telecoms
shares had lost 95 per cent of their value; some $2.5 trillion of market
capitalisation had gone up in smoke. Telecoms debt now stands at around $525
billion - more than the value of the outstanding junk bonds at the end of the
1980s and the cost of the Savings and Loan bail-out combined.
Because telecoms accounted
for such a disproportionate share of capital accumulation, the reverberations
of its collapse were immense. By 2000 the industry was responsible for 12 per
cent of spending on equipment in the US economy. But telecoms investment
plunged by 40 per cent over the next two years. Since December 2000 telecoms
companies with a combined worth of $230 billion have gone bankrupt, and 60 per
cent of all corporate defaults have come from this sector. During the same
period, the industry laid off more than half a million workers - 50 per cent
more than it had hired in the spectacular expansion between 1996 and 2000. By
comparison, the car industry took two decades to reduce employment from 1.5
million to 732,000.
The declining orders of
telecoms carriers have hammered the profitability of their suppliers, among
them most of the leading lights of the high-tech boom - Cisco Systems, Lucent, Nortel,
Motorola - which have sustained catastrophic collapses in share prices and
financial conditions. Their problems, in turn, dealt a heavy blow to their own
suppliers. Stock-market darlings such as JDS Uniphase and Sycamore have fallen
into oblivion. The semiconductor industry - hard-hit by the steep drop in
computer sales, as well as the telecoms fall-off - entered its worst downturn
since the early 1980s. All told, the chain reactions set off by the telecoms
crash were responsible for around a quarter of the decline in economic growth
between the first half of 2000 and the first half of 2001; and thus, to a
disproportionate extent, for the economy's fall into recession in 2001.
The problems in telecoms
overlapped with a more general crisis in the high-tech sector, especially in
computers and semiconductors. The depth of this crisis was revealed in an
analysis, published on 16 August 2001 in the Wall Street Journal, of the 4200
companies listed on the Nasdaq Stock Index. The losses these firms reported in
the 12 months following 1 July 2000 amounted to $148.3 billion - in other
words, slightly more than the $145.3 billion profits they had reported during
the five-year boom of 1995 to 2000. As one economist commented: 'What it means
is that, with the benefit of hindsight, the late 1990s never happened.' The
high-tech crisis itself unfolded in the context of a broader US economy already
weighed down by overcapacity in international manufacturing. By early 2002, the
profit rate in the corporate manufacturing sector had fallen, from its peak in
1997, by 42 per cent. Profitability in the non-financial corporate sector as a
whole was at its lowest level during the postwar period (with the exceptions of
1980 and 1982).
Under the impact of the
collapse of equity prices and the crisis of profitability, the growth of output
and investment fell faster between mid-2000 and mid-2001 than at any other time
since World War Two. This is all the more understandable in view of the fact
that, according to the Council of Economic Advisers, the information technology
sector, which constituted just 8 per cent of GDP, accounted for almost a third
of all growth of GDP between 1995 and 1999. GDP growth dropped from 5 per cent
to minus 0.1 per cent (on an annualised basis). Non-residential investment
growth fell from 9 per cent to minus 5 per cent. In response, US corporations
have been severely reducing their means of production and, in particular, their
labour forces in an effort to restore competitiveness, placing huge pressure on
their rivals to respond in kind. Since the first quarter of 2000, manufacturing
employment (measured in hours) has been reduced by a stunning 13.8 per cent.
The overall effect has been a powerful downward spiral in which pressure on
prices resulting from overcapacity has led to falling profitability, which has
issued in falling investment, making for rising unemployment and bankruptcies
and, in turn, reductions in demand that have fed back into falling prices and
profitability, and so on.
As the US has entered its
cyclical downturn, the rest of the world has been dragged down too. Under the
impact of plummeting US imports, the economies of Japan, Europe and East Asia
began to lose steam, which caused a further sharp drop in US exports, further
depressing growth. This mutually reinforcing, international recessionary
process is all the more worrying because of the extent to which the economies
of the rest of the world have, over the past two decades, in the face of
stagnating domestic demand, come to depend on exports and thus on a US economy
that can, as a result, look to no one but itself to bail it out.
Beginning in January 2001,
the Federal Reserve lowered interest rates on 12 occasions, the cuts amounting
to a staggering 5.25 per cent, down to today's record postwar low of 1.25 per
cent. But, with respect to corporations, it has been pushing on Keynes's
proverbial string, eliciting no reaction. Investment in plants and equipment,
the key to economic health, has fallen every single quarter since autumn 2000,
driving the recession.
Households, by contrast,
have taken advantage of cheap credit, and have increased their borrowing at an
even faster rate than during the boom, especially by refinancing their
mortgages. As a result of this, consumer expenditure continued to rise, and was
almost entirely responsible for cutting short the economy's downward spiral of
2001, restoring stability at least temporarily. Washington hopes that consumer
spending will hold up long enough for corporations to work off their excess
capacity. But the worry is that the overhang of plant and equipment will
continue to forestall further capital investment, and that consumer spending
will peter out in the face of rising unemployment and unsustainable levels of
debt.
While the Fed's easy credit
policy has brought a semblance of order, it has also, in so doing, helped to
perpetuate three enormous imbalances left over from the bubble, thus increasing
the potential magnitude of disaster. The first is that of share values
themselves. Equity prices have, of course, fallen sharply. However, their
decline has failed to bring stock values back into line with profits, because
these have fallen even further. At the end of 2001, the S&P composite index
had declined by about 25 per cent from its mid-2000 peak, but the
price-earnings ratio of its corporations had actually increased by about 25 per
cent. No doubt, cheap credit has helped keep shares overpriced, making the
business climate seem sunnier. But a serious 'correction' now could wreck the economy.
Second, in 2002, US trade
and current-account deficits broke all records. Until recently, overseas
investors have been more than willing to fund these deficits, making huge
direct investments in the US, and buying up corporate equities and bonds. But
as the American economy and stock market have continued to disappoint, the rest
of the world has sharply reduced its buying, and its equity purchases fell by
83 per cent in 2002 compared to 2000. As a result of this disenchantment,
pressure on the currency has mounted and the dollar has fallen by 16 per cent
against the euro in the space of a year. If these trends continue, the Federal
Reserve could soon be faced with an excruciating choice: either let the dollar
fall and risk a wholesale liquidation of US properties by foreign investors -
which might not only wreak havoc in the asset markets but also set off a real
run on the dollar - or raise interest rates and risk pushing the economy back
into deep recession.
Finally, although corporate
borrowing has fallen sharply over the past two years, the further step up in
household borrowing during that period has enabled total private debt to rocket
high above its record level at the peak of the boom, even in the face of rising
joblessness. What made this possible was a huge run-up in housing prices that
was itself driven not only by rock bottom interest rates, but also by major
fund transfers to real estate from an ailing stock market. The appreciation of
real estate values has enabled homeowners to treat their houses like ATMs:
according to a recent study by Goldman Sachs, in the third quarter of 2002
Americans netted an astounding $320 billion (on an annualised basis) from their
homes. But should the housing bubble burst, or even stop inflating, households,
their home equity already profoundly depleted, would have to cut back their
borrowing. Consumer spending would then have to be sharply reduced, threatening
the main prop to the recovery.
In December 2002, the Fed
reduced the cost of borrowing by a further half point, tantamount to an
admission that its enormous easing of credit over the previous two years had
been insufficient to restart the economy. The Fed made the point even clearer
by worrying publicly that, as a result of unused industrial capacity and the
rise in unemployment, price increases were too low and perhaps declining,
making for downward pressure on incomes. Falling profits in the second and
third quarters of 2002 seemed to substantiate the Fed's concern. Subsequent
assurances by Chairman Greenspan and the Fed Governor, Ben Bernanke, that
deflation was only a remote possibility - and could in any case easily be
countered by the Fed's printing money - naturally had an effect opposite to
that intended.
After more than a decade in
which the balanced budget had assumed quasi-religious status, many were
suddenly converted to the necessity of a major dose of deficit spending. The
Bush Administration seemed to come to the rescue with a programme designed to
intensify a good deal further a stimulus that was already growing. But it was
soon evident that, just as the Bush response to 9/11 was a war on Iraq that
Cheney, Rumsfeld et al had been planning for more than a decade, the Bush
response to the faltering economy was the tax cuts for the wealthy that had
been the first item on his agenda and that of the Republican Party since the
day he left his ranch, backed up by increases in arms spending to support the
long-mooted Middle East campaigns. And just as the war on Iraq and related
military expenditures promised to deliver little in the way of increased
security to American citizens, the constituent elements of the Bush deficit
offered little in the way of stimulus. The fact remains that, thanks to 9/11
and the weakening economy, the Bush Administration has been able to launch a
reprise of Ronald Reagan's programme in a way that would have seemed
inconceivable only two and a half years ago.
The key elements of the Bush
tax plan involve moving forward to 2003 reductions in the rate of taxation on
incomes in the highest brackets that had previously been scheduled for 2004 and
2006, as well as abolishing tax on dividends. Since these tax cuts are confined
to the better off and since, according to the New York University economist
Edward Wolff, the top 10 per cent in the income spectrum hold approximately 85
per cent of the value of taxable stocks and mutual funds (the top 1 per cent
hold approximately 49 per cent), it is easy to guess who will benefit.
According to the Washington-based Citizens for Tax Justice, the top 10 per cent
would receive about 60 per cent of the gains, while the top 1 per cent, with
incomes of over $1 million, would average gains of $30,000 apiece. How would
this produce the hoped for stimulus? According to the Administration, the elimination
of the dividend tax will increase the value of equities, with the consequence
that the beneficiaries of the plan will plough the money they save back into
the stock market, leading to an increase in share prices, in the most
optimistic estimate, of as much as 10 per cent. Almost unbelievably, the way
being charted to revive the economy is to reinflate the bubble.
The other, implicit plank of
the Administration's stimulus programme has been developing since Bush took
office, and especially since 9/11. In 2001 and 2002, military spending grew by
6 per cent and 10 per cent respectively, amounting to about 65 per cent and 80
per cent respectively of the total increases in Federal spending in these
years. Since the military budget of the US was already larger than that of the
next 25 countries taken together, and since it is also 26 times the size of the
combined spending of the seven countries traditionally identified by the
Pentagon as the US's most likely adversaries (Cuba, Iran, Iraq, Libya, North Korea,
Sudan and Syria), it is not easy to see these increases as indispensable for
the nation's security. The current military strength of Iraq, the US's
immediate target, is by all accounts perhaps a third of what it was in 1991.
Nevertheless, military expenditure is unquestionably providing the
Administration's most direct stimulus to the economy, as registered in the fact
that, in the year following 9/11, the equities of the nation's nine largest
defence contractors performed 30 per cent better than those of the S&P500.
Since early 2000, the
Federal budget deficit has risen sharply, as a percentage of GDP, to 1.8 per
cent from a surplus of 2.3 per cent, and will certainly go higher. But, up
against corporations gorged with plant and equipment, and households up to
their ears in debt and close to spent out, the deficit is probably insufficient
to provide more than a limited boost to growth. Yet it is unlikely that the
Bush administration is much concerned about this. Its abolition of the tax on
dividends and reduction of rates on high earners would take effect in 2004 at
the earliest. These measures would, moreover, sharply reduce revenue to
money-strapped state governments, counteracting the Federal stimulus by forcing
many of them to cut back on spending. Administration spokespeople and
Republican Congressional leaders have made it very clear that, like Reagan
before them, they intend to control the deficit they are creating by reining in
non-military spending. To emphasise the point, they have already defeated a
proposal to extend unemployment insurance for workers whose benefits are
exhausted, and are insisting that a greater number of people be removed from
welfare, despite the declining availability of jobs. Measures that would
sharply raise purchasing power right away by placing money in the hands of
working people - such as immediate reductions in payroll taxes, subsidies to
allow states to maintain spending on health and social services, or
straightforward bonuses to workers - are anathema to this Administration. In
much the same way as the Bush Government's plans for national security are
about the projection of US military might in the Middle East and beyond, its
economic stimulus programme is about the transfer of wealth from the poor to
the already wealthy. Bush and his advisers are evidently counting on the
economy to right itself. The fact remains that Wall Street analysts were
reporting in late January that the economy had probably contracted in the
fourth quarter of 2002: either the recession was worsening or the dreaded
double dip had begun. For the first time, public opinion polls are recording
less than 50 per cent approval of the Administration's handling of economic
affairs and, perhaps not unrelatedly, that citizen support for the war on Iraq
is down. The road ahead, for the US economy and for the Bush Administration, is
going to be a rocky one.
Robert Brenner is the director of the
Center for Social Theory and Comparative History at UCLA, and the author of The
Boom and the Bubble (Verso, 2002). Posted with author’s permission.